Finance

Stimulus Policies Should Better Consider Our Fiscal Future

President Joe Biden’s inbound COVID relief proposal was released last week, touting an additional $1.9 trillion in semi-targeted economic support. If Congress passes the plan as-is, it will combine with December’s $900 billion aid package for a total additional emergency response equal to 13 percent of GDP, more than 25 percent including all of last year’s emergency allocations.

While both parties tend to agree, along with a majority of Americans, that Congress has to continue to borrow and spend right now to keep us afloat, few have given the consideration to our future fiscal policy direction that we all deserve.

Biden’s new plan puts a lot up for debate, as any grand plan from a new president will. Certainly, there is a need for continued support for the unemployed, those in tenuous housing situations, families struggling to afford food — and of course we should do anything in our power to help the health care system eradicate COVID, while opening schools and businesses before the onset of unrecoverable permanent effects. However, similarly sized economic relief checks, unemployment benefit extensions and state and local relief had substantially lower-than-expected returns in 2020.

The girth of the proposed unemployment benefit expansion and minimum wage adjustments within the Biden proposal may also have unexpectedly adverse effects. Both have honorable objectives, but too much in unemployment can shrink the labor pool when employers are clamoring for workers, while some contend that outsized minimum wages will reduce the incentive to draw from whatever labor pool does exist. Legislators should be wary of the diminishing returns to increases in these investments.

With cheap borrowing rates and a high downside risk to not getting it right, one can understand the temptation to go big. Janet Yellen argued as much before the Senate Finance Committee this week, but Congress’ job is to pare ambition and consider recent data to choose the best policy path, further placing weight on the future fiscal policy implications of today’s relief packages.

Having already surpassed the size of the economy in 2020 for the first time since World War II, our national debt is only expected to increase in the near term, exacerbating the risk of over-extending our financial resources.  Rising debts correlate with slowing economic performance and reduced individual income potential as we spend more on interest and less on good investments.  The cost to service our debt alone, for example, is expected to pass the amount we spend on national defense in a couple of decades, likely sooner if rates shift (and they will).

Counterarguments suggest that risks are mitigated if we simply lend to ourselves, historic drops in interest rates will continue to reduce borrowing costs and the economy will grow fast enough to cover any additional debt burden. But are we confident enough in our estimates to wager the next generation? It is almost impossible to predict shifting sentiment and building interest rate risks, which often change rapidly and are amplified by larger debt loads.  Further, while we can make our best guesses, we can’t predict whether future shocks will lead to insurmountable hiccups in our outlook on growth (e.g., 2020).

A responsible addition to this year’s COVID counterattack will include policies that temper our debt trajectory, remove the need for legislative intervention in the next crisis and provide parameters to eventually reduce the deficit. We have a number of automatic stabilizers in place that can use a bit of revision — for example, allowing for larger swings of fiscal support when necessary, cutting back faster when the good times return.

If there is anything that the Great Recession and the Great COVID Lockdown have proven, it is that legislators can’t act fast or firmly enough, will always get it wrong to some extent and will necessarily pass unrelated extras while we are distracted. It is an imperfect art that we hope will end in our favor, but pre-emptive planning can prevent waste and ensure the timeliness of implementation.

When COVID is finally eradicated, or we learn to live with it, we need to ensure a methodical, unbiased and politically apathetic approach to slowing the spigot. There are many solid proposals that will slow deficits without crimping growth, without requiring harsh austerity measures.

A controlled, long-term approach that ensures harmless deficit reductions can have a lasting and positive effect on our economic future. In fact, my own research covering time periods over the last four decades found that deficit reductions can improve economic performance almost immediately – if done properly – with benefits lasting well into the future.

It’s difficult to conduct a thoughtful and well-planned policy approach when faced with an unexpected and unprecedented crisis, which is why better long-term fiscal policy plans should have been enacted during our recent growth spurts. Fortunately, we are not in over our heads yet. There is still time for a beneficial approach to long-term fiscal sustainability, and it should be included in today’s policies.

Justin Vélez-Hagan, Ph.D., is the principal advisor of Macro Policy Advisors and author of the books “The Paradox of Fiscal Austerity” and “The Common Sense Behind Basic Economics.”

Morning Consult welcomes op-ed submissions on policy, politics and business strategy in our coverage areas. Updated submission guidelines can be found here.

Morning Consult